CAN SUSTAINABLE MANAGEMENT SAVE TROPICAL FORESTS? |
Sustainability proves surprisingly problematic in the quest to reconcile conservation with the production of tropical timber
To those of us who have dedicated careers to conserving the
biodiversity and natural splendor of the earth's woodlands, the ongoing
destruction of tropical rain forest is a constant source of distress.
These lush habitats shelter a rich array of flora and fauna, only a
small fraction of which scientists have properly investigated. Yet
deforestation in the tropics continues relentlessly and on a vast
scale--driven, in part, by the widespread logging of highly prized
tropical woods.
In an effort to reverse this tide, many conservationists have
embraced the notion of carefully regulated timber production as a
compromise between strict preservation and uncontrolled exploitation.
Forest management is an attractive strategy because, in theory, it
reconciles the economic interests of producers with the needs of
conservation. In practice, sustainable management requires both
restraint in cutting trees and investment in replacing them by planting
seedlings or by promoting the natural regeneration of harvested
species.
Most conservationists view this formula as a pragmatic scheme for
countries that can ill afford to forgo using their valuable timber. We,
too, favored this strategy until recently, when we reluctantly
concluded that most of the well-meaning efforts in this direction by
environmental advocates, forest managers and international aid agencies
had a very slim chance for success. Although our concerns about the
effectiveness of sustainable forestry have since mounted, our initial
disillusionment sprang from our experiences trying to foster such
practices in South America seven years ago.
It was our interest in trying to preserve the Amazonian rain forests
of Bolivia that brought two of us together for the first time in 1990,
for a chance meeting at the bar of the sleepy Hotel El Dorado in
downtown La Paz. Gullison had just arrived from Princeton University to
conduct research on the ecology of mahogany (Swietenia macrophylla
King), the most valuable species in the tropical Americas. Rice was
about to return to Washington, D.C., after working with the Smithsonian
Institution at the Beni Biosphere Reserve, located next to the Chimanes
Permanent Timber Production Forest, a tract of half a million hectares
in lowland Bolivia. In the mid-1980s the International Tropical Timber
Organization selected the Chimanes Forest as a model site for
sustainable management, and we were both eager to help that program
advance.
Although our first exchange over beer in La Paz was brief, by the
end of the conversation we had agreed to collaborate further. Within a
year we secured funding for what eventually became a four-year study.
At the outset, our intention was for Gullison to establish how best to
manage mahogany production from an ecological standpoint and for Rice
to develop the economic arguments needed to convince timber companies
to adopt policies based on these scientific findings.
As time passed, Gullison and his Bolivian field crew made steady
progress in understanding the ecology of the forest. Mahogany
seedlings, it turned out, grew and prospered only after sizable natural
disturbances. In the Chimanes region, younger mahogany trees stood only
near rivers where floods had recently swept the banks clear and buried
competing vegetation under a thick blanket of sediment. Such
disturbances in the past had created widely dispersed pockets where
seedlings could grow, eventually producing groups of trees of
approximately uniform age and size. For the problem at hand, this
aspect of the ecology of mahogany was quite alarming: it meant that
uncontrolled logging would invariably obliterate the older stands,
where nearly all trees would be of a marketable size.
Those worries were exacerbated by the realization that there would
be little natural growth to replace harvested trees even if the loggers
cut the forest sparingly. Mahogany seedlings (and those of certain
other tropical tree species) cannot grow under the shady canopy of
dense tropical forest. With natural regeneration unlikely to prove
adequate, human intervention would be needed to maintain the mahogany
indefinitely.
How could a helping hand be provided? In theory, loggers could
create the proper conditions for new mahogany to grow by mimicking
nature and clearing large openings in the forest. But the effort would
be enormous, and judging from previous attempts elsewhere to do just
that, costly periodic "thinnings", would be required to remove
competing vegetation. Such efforts to sustain the production of
mahogany could disturb so much forest that the overall conservation
objectives would surely be compromised. Hence, winning the battle for
mahogany might still lose the war to preserve biodiversity.
Appreciation of this difficulty led us to question what exactly it was
we were trying to achieve.
Just as Gullison was discovering the difficulties of regenerating
mahogany, Rice was finding that timber companies working in the
Chimanes Forest had no economic incentive to invest in sustainable
management. This conclusion was not entirely surprising given global
trends: less than one eighth of 1 percent of the world's tropical
production forests were operating on a sustained-yield basis as of the
late 1980s. Logging, as typically practiced in the tropics, rapidly
harvests the most highly valued trees. The number of species extracted
may be as low as one (where there is a specialty wood, such as
mahogany) or as high as 80 to 90 (where there is demand for a wide
variety). Logging companies generally show little concern for the
condition of residual stands and make no investment in regeneration.
This attitude emerges, in part, as a matter of simple economics. In
deciding whether to restrict harvests, companies face a choice between
cutting trees immediately and banking the profits or delaying the
harvest and allowing the stand to grow in volume and value over time.
Economics, it seems, dictates the decision.
In choosing the first option, a company would harvest its trees as
quickly as possible, invest the proceeds and earn the going rate of
return, which can be measured by real, or inflation-adjusted, interest
rates. Because risks are considerable and capital is scarce, real
interest rates in developing countries are often much higher than in
industrial countries. For example, real interest rates on
dollar-denominated accounts in Bolivia have averaged 17 percent in
recent years, compared with 4 percent in the U.S. Similarly high rates
of interest are common in most countries in Latin America. Thus,
companies that rapidly harvest their assets can invest their profits
immediately and generate continuing high rates of return.
The benefits of delaying, harvests, in contrast, are small. From
1987 to 1994, real price increases for mahogany averaged 1 percent a
year, whereas the average annual growth in volume of commercial-size
mahogany trees is typically less than 4 percent. This combination of
slow growth rates and modest price increases means that mahogany trees
(as well as most other commercial tree species in the American tropics)
rise in value annually by at most 4 to 5 percent -- about the same as
would be earned by a conservative investment in the U.S. and much less
than competitive returns in Bolivia.
The value of the trees left to grow, moreover, could easily plummet
if wind, fire or disease destroyed them or if in the future the
government restricted logging. Therefore, choosing to leave mahogany
growing amounts to a rather uncertain investment -- one that would
provide, at most, a rate of return that is essentially the same as
could be obtained by harvesting the trees and banking the profits
safely. Like most other business-people, who are unwilling to make
risky investments in developing countries unless offered considerably
higher returns, loggers choose to cut their trees as quickly as they
can.
After making a careful analysis of the economics of logging in the
Chimanes region, we discovered that unrestricted logging is from two to
five times more profitable than logging in a way that would ensure a
continued supply of mahogany. From a purely financial perspective,
then, the most rational approach to logging appears to be exactly what
timber companies are doing -- harvesting all the available mahogany
first, avoiding investments in future harvests, and then moving on in
sequence to all species that yield a positive net return. Adam Smith's
invisible hand, it appears, reaches deep into the rain forest.
The incentives driving uncontrolled logging prove especially
powerful in developing countries, where government regulation is, in
general, quite weak. The national forest authority in Bolivia, for
instance, receives annually less than 30 cents for each hectare of land
it administers. (The U.S. Forest Service, in comparison, gets about
$44.) With such slim support government regulators in Bolivia are
hard-pressed to counterbalance the financial rewards of cutting all the
valuable trees at once, and it is no wonder that few timber companies
there invest any effort to help the targeted species regenerate.
After spending some time in the Chimanes region of Bolivia, we
decided to investigate how severely logging there had injured the local
environment. We quickly found that, although clearly unsustainable for
mahogany, the physical effects of logging on the forest as a whole have
been relatively mild. Because only one or two mahogany trees grow in a
typical 10-hectare plot, road building, felling and log removal disrupt
less than 5 percent of the land. We estimate that current logging
practice causes considerably less damage than some forms of sustainable
management (which require more intensive harvests of a wider variety of
species). Indeed, a more sustainable approach could well double the
harm inflicted by logging.
Sustainability is, in fact, a poor guide to the environmental harm
caused by timber operations. Logging that is unsustainable-that is,
incapable of maintaining production of the desired species
indefinitely-need not be highly damaging (although in some forests it
is, especially where a wide range of species have commercial value).
Likewise, sustainable logging does not necessarily guarantee a low
environmental toll. Ideally, companies should manage forests in a way
that is both sustainable for timber and minimally disturbing to the
environment. But when forced to choose between unsustainable,
low-impact logging and sustainable, high-impact logging,
environmentalists should make sure they pick the option that best meets
their conservation objectives. If the maintenance of biodiversity is of
paramount importance -- as we believe it should be -- a low-impact
(albeit unsustainable) approach may be the preferable choice.
Yet the quest to sustain the yield of wood indefinitely has become a
central theme in efforts to preserve tropical forests. And
conservation-minded people have proposed several strategies to overcome
the economic obstacles to sustainable forest management. Their
approaches, however, often fail to distinguish between the
profitability of logging existing forests and the profitability of
investing in regeneration. In the absence of strong governmental
control, both must be financially attractive to succeed.
Efforts to increase the utilization of lesser known tree species
provide an informative example. Some advocates of sustainable
management contend that boosting market demand for lesser known species
will make it worthwhile to maintain a production forest that otherwise
might be convened to farmland or rangeland. Yet there is nothing --
such as faster growth or a brighter price outlook -- to suggest that
investments in regenerating these species will be any more attractive
than investments in regenerating currently targeted species. Larger
markets for secondary species may only increase the number of trees
that are harvested unsustainably.
A parallel argument can be made with regard to secondary, or
value-added, processing. Such processing (of logs into furniture or
plywood) is often said to have the dual advantages of allowing the use
of a wider variety of species while providing a stronger economic
incentive to manage forests sustainably. In fact, the promotion of
value-added processing many countries has actually reduced their
overall earnings (because large subsidies are needed to attract the
necessary investment) while greatly increasing both the pace and scale
of forest destruction.
Arguments promoting, secure land tenure suffer from a similar
limitation. Environmental advocates point to the lack of long term
access to timber resources as a major cause of unsustainable
management. The commonsense argument favoring tenure security is that,
without it, timber companies will be reluctant to invest in future
harvests. Yet ensuring that companies are, in principle, able to
benefit from nurturing forest growth does nothing to provide the
practical financial incentives to foster such practices. More secure
land tenure makes investments in regeneration possible for timber
companies to consider; it does not, however, automatically make these
investments economically worthwhile. In fact, rather than promoting
investments in regeneration, more secure tenure may simply lower the
risk of making larger investments in logging equipment, thus
encouraging swifter liquidation of the resource.
This very issue brought Reid to our team in 1994. Rice had met Reid
two years earlier in a torrential storm in the heart of the Peten,
Guatemala's heavily forested northern province. Logging there had been
suspended by government decree, but Guatemala's policymakers were
considering turning large tracts of forest over to companies under
contracts that would have endured for 25 years.
We agreed that such lengthy tenure for loggers probably would not
solve the problems of unsustainable logging and an expanding,
agricultural frontier. It could, we feared, hurt the thousands of
people who roam these woods in search of chicle latex (a gum),
ornamental palm leaves and allspice -- all valuable products for
export. So when local authorities drafted a proposal to allow timber
interests long-term concessions in hopes of promoting sustainable
management, Rice called Reid to ask whether he would like to examine
that policy in detail. Six weeks later the Guatemalan government had
our report, which demonstrated the hefty cut in profits that companies
would have to absorb to manage these forests sustainably. As a result,
the plan was shelved, although pressure remains to turn the forest over
to the logging industry.
Many people concerned with the future of the rain forest view timber
certification, or "green labeling," as the prime means of providing the
economic incentive needed to spur sustainable management. Such
certification programs call for voluntary compliance with established
environmental standards in exchange for higher prices or greater market
access, or both. While experts debate whether certification actually
leads to higher market prices, the more important question is whether
the premiums consumers are willing to pay for certified products are
sufficient to bring about the necessary changes. Our economic analysis
of the Chimanes operations indicated that for valuable species such as
mahogany, current patterns of unsustainable logging can be as much as
five times as profitable as a more sustainable alternative. Yet
consumers appear to be willing to spend, at most, 10 percent more for
certified timber than the price they would pay for uncertified wood
products. The gap is enormous.
Nevertheless, certification has the potential to be an important
tool for forest conservation, as long as these efforts concentrate on
low-cost modifications that are sure to reduce environmental damage
(such as preventing loggers from hunting forest animals) rather than
expensive changes that bring doubtful benefits. Although there is not
yet broad consumer demand for certified wood, there does appear to be a
growing niche that could be filled if the costs of being green are kept
to a minimum. In the meantime, it would be best to avoid altering the
economic incentives facing all logging operations, such as increasing
tenure security or promoting lesser known species, simply to benefit
the small number involved with certification. Without much broader
acceptance of certification, such policies may only speed the
degradation of tropical forests.
The management of tropical forests for sustainable timber production
is unlikely to become a widespread phenomenon, at least in the near
future. Contrary economic incentives, limited government control and a
lack of local political support will consistently thwart the best
efforts in that direction, particularly in developing countries.
Environmentalists need to recognize this reality. Although we see no
easy solutions, there are a few strategies that deserve greater
attention.
One possibility is to provide timber companies with low-interest
loans to fund regeneration and the protection of biodiversity. Logging
that includes these activities is not sufficiently profitable at the
high interest rates typical in developing countries, but it could
become so if funded by cheaper capital, perhaps provided by development
banks or conscientious investors.
Another option is to promote the preservation of large forested
areas within and around timber concessions. Such set-asides would be
relatively inexpensive to monitor and could aid substantially in the
conservation of biodiversity. Rather than just keeping forest cover,
such protected areas as could maintain forest that had nearly its full
complement of species and old-growth structure. Ideally, these lands
should be contiguous with, or near, other intact forest. To minimize
the cost, we suggest focusing on commercially inoperable areas, such as
places too steep to log or forests that have been lightly logged in the
past.
Although such set-asides may be among the less economically
productive areas under their control, timber companies are likely to
resist any restrictions at all on their movements. In Bolivia the
government is addressing this difficulty by offering loggers a
financial reward for preservation. Under a law that has just been
approved, the Bolivian government will collect a flat tax (of around $1
per hectare a year) for logging privileges. Timber companies can,
however, designate up to 30 percent of their concessions as off-limits
to logging, and the lands thus specified will be exempt from taxation.
This policy should encourage loggers to protect their commercially
marginal lands, and it may soften their resistance to having other
areas set aside for the protection of the environment.
Finally, in forests such as Chimanes, where uncontrolled logging is
selective and settlement pressures are low, accepting some elements of
the status quo may prove to be the best available option. As in many
areas of the Bolivian lowlands, logging in Chimanes is almost certain
to continue long after the mahogany has been exhausted. In fact, the
current pattern of selective harvest of a large number of commercial
species, one or two species at a time, is a process that in some areas
could require decades to complete. The challenge facing
conservationists under such circumstances is not so much to convince
the timber companies to stay and log sustainably for the long run hut
rather to institute some form of protection for old-growth forests
while the opportunity remains.
Environmentalists also need to remember that many threats to
tropical forests would continue even if sustainable management were to
become widely adopted. National agricultural policies, road development
and colonization can each pose a far greater danger to tropical forests
than unsustainable logging. Reducing the destruction caused by these
forces could do much more for forest conservation than revamping
current forestry practices.
Clearly, no single strategy will work indefinitely or for all
forests. Our prescriptions (particularly for old-growth set-asides)
might ultimately succumb to the same forces that now frustrate
sustainable forest management. Over time, producers will have an ever
greater incentive to enter currently uneconomic areas. So, in the
absence of determined government oversight, these alternatives, too,
would fail just as surely as efforts to impose sustainable forestry.
Our set-aside proposal differs, however, in that it delivers real and
immediate environmental benefits by protecting old-growth forest.
Furthermore, it relies on straightforward restrictions about where
logging occurs rather than on complicated technical rules dictating how
logging is to be done.
Although far from providing fully satisfying solutions, the measures
we suggest may be the most realistic means to harmonize conservation
with tropical timber extraction, until such time as political and
economic change in the developing world brings a widespread demand for
more effective protection of these majestic tropical forests.
~~~~~~~~
by Richard E. Rice, Raymond E. Gullison and John W. Reid
RICHARD E. RICE, RAYMOND E. GULLISON and JOHN W. REID came to study
the problems of tropical forests from quite different perspectives.
Rice obtained a bachelor's degree in economics at Grinnell College and
went on to earn a master's in economics and, in 1983, a doctorate in
natural resources from the University of Michigan. He is currently the
senior director of the resource economics program at Conservation
International in Washington, D.C. After graduating from the University
of British Columbia with a degree in zoology, Gullison studied ecology
and evolutionary biology at Princeton University, where he completed a
Ph.D. in 1995. He now teaches at the Imperial College of Science,
Technology and Medicine in London. Reid earned a master's degree in
public policy at Harvard University before joining Conservation
International ill 1994. His work there focuses on natural resource
economics and policy issues concerning conservation in the tropics.