POPULATION, POVERTY AND THE LOCAL ENVIRONMENT |
As forests and rivers recede, a child's labor can become more
valuable to parents, spurring a vicious cycle that traps families in
poverty
As with politics, we all have widely differing opinions about
population. Some would point to population growth as the cause of
poverty and environmental degradation. Others would permute the
elements of this causal chain, arguing, for example, that poverty is
the cause rather than the consequence of increasing numbers. Yet even
when studying the semi-arid regions of sub-Saharan Africa and the
Indian subcontinent, economists have typically not regarded poverty,
population growth and the local environment as interconnected. Inquiry
into each factor has in large measure gone along its own narrow route,
with discussion of their interactions dominated by popular
writings--which, although often illuminating, are in the main
descriptive and not analytical.
Over the past several years, though, a few investigators have
studied the relations between these ingredients more closely. Our
approach fuses theoretical modeling with empirical findings drawn from
a number of disciplines, such as anthropology, demography, ecology,
economics, nutrition and political science. Focusing on the vast
numbers of small, rural communities in the poorest regions of the
world, the work has identified circumstances in which population
growth, poverty and degradation of local resources often fuel one
another. The collected research has shown that none of the three
elements directly causes the other two; rather each influences, and is
in turn influenced by, the others. This new perspective has significant
implications for policies aimed at improving life for some of the
world's most impoverished inhabitants.
In contrast with this new perspective, with its focus on local
experience, popular tracts on the environment and population growth
have usually taken a global view. They have emphasized the deleterious
effects that a large population would have on our planet in the distant
future. Although that slant has its uses, it has drawn attention away
from the economic misery endemic today. Disaster is not something the
poorest have to wait for: it is occurring even now. Besides, in
developing countries, decisions on whether to have a child and on how
to share education, food, work, health care and local resources are in
large measure made within small entities such as households. So it
makes sense to study the link between poverty, population growth and
the environment from a myriad of local, even individual, viewpoints.
The household assumes various guises in different parts of the
world. Some years ago Gary S. Becker of the University of Chicago was
the first investigator to grapple with this difficulty. He used an
idealized version of the concept to explore how choices made within a
household would respond to changes in the outside world, such as
employment opportunities and availability of credit, insurance, health
care and education.
One problem with his method, as I saw it when I began my own work
some five years ago, was that it studied households in isolation; it
did not investigate the dynamics between interacting units. In addition
to understanding the forces that encouraged couples to favor large
families, I wanted to understand the ways in which a reasoned decision
to have children, made by each household, could end up being
detrimental to all households.
In studying how such choices are made, I found a second problem with
the early approach: by assuming that decision making was shared equally
by adults, investigators had taken an altogether too benign view of the
process. Control over a family's choices is, after all, often held
unequally. If I wanted to understand how decisions were made, I would
have to know who was doing the deciding.
Those who enjoy the greatest power within a family can often be
identified by the way the household's resources are divided. Judith
Bruce of the Population Council, Mayra Buvinic of the International
Center for Research on Women, Lincoln C. Chen and Amartya Sen of
Harvard University and others have observed that the sharing of
resources within a household is often unequal even when differences in
needs are taken into account. In poor households in the Indian
subcontinent, for example, men and boys usually get more sustenance
than do women and girls, and the elderly get less than the young.
Such inequities prevail over fertility choices as well. Here also
men wield more influence, even though women typically bear the greater
cost. To grasp how great the burden can be, consider the number of live
babies a woman would normally have if she managed to survive through
her childbearing years. This number, called the total fertility rate,
is between six and eight in sub-Saharan Africa. Each successful birth
there involves at least a year and a half of pregnancy and
breast-feeding. So in a society where female life expectancy at birth
is 50 years and the fertility rate is, say, seven, nearly half of a
woman's adult life is spent either carrying a child in her womb or
breast-feeding it. And this calculation does not allow for unsuccessful
pregnancies.
Another indicator of the price that women pay is maternal mortality.
In most poor countries, complications related to pregnancy constitute
the largest single cause of death of women in their reproductive years.
In some parts of sub-Saharan Africa as many as one woman dies for every
50 live births. (The rate in Scandinavia today is one per 20,000.) At a
total fertility rate of seven or more, the chance that a woman entering
her reproductive years will not live through them is about one in six.
Producing children therefore involves playing a kind of Russian
roulette.
Given such a high cost of procreation, one expects that women, given
a choice, would opt for fewer children. But are birth rates in fact
highest in societies where women have the least power within the
family? Data on the status of women from 79 so-called Third World
countries display an unmistakable pattern: high fertility, high rates
of illiteracy, low share of paid employment and a high percentage
working at home for no pay--they all hang together. From the statistics
alone it is difficult to discern which of these factors are causing,
and which are merely correlated with, high fertility. But the findings
are consistent with the possibility that lack of paid employment and
education limits a woman's ability to make decisions and therefore
promotes population growth.
There is also good reason to think that lack of income-generahng
employment reduces women's power more directly than does lack of
education. Such an insight has implications for policy. It is all well
and good, for example, to urge governments in poor countries to invest
in literacy programs. But the results could be disappointing. Many
factors militate against poor households' taking advantage of
subsidized education. If children are needed to work inside and outside
the home, then keeping them in school (even a cheap one) is costly. In
patrilineal societies, educated girls can also be perceived as less
pliable and harder to marry off. Indeed, the benefits of subsidies to
even primary education are reaped disproportionately by families that
are better off.
In contrast, policies aimed at increasing women's productivity at
home and improving their earnings in the marketplace would directly
empower them, especially within the family. Greater earning power for
women would also raise for men the implicit costs of procreation (which
keeps women from bringing m cash income). This is not to deny the value
of public investment in primary and secondary education in developing
countries. It is only to say we should be wary of claims that such
investment is a panacea for the population problem.
The importance of gender inequality to overpopulation in poor
nations is fortunately gaining international recognition. Indeed, the
United Nations Conference on Population and Development held in Cairo
in September 1994 emphasized women's reproductive rights and the means
by which they could be protected and promoted. But there is more to the
population problem than gender inequalities. Even when both parents
participate in the decision to have a child, there are several pathways
through which the choice becomes harmful to the community. These routes
have been uncovered by inquiring into the various motives for
procreation.
One motive, common to humankind, relates to children as ends in
themselves. It ranges from the desire to have children because they are
playful and enjoyable, to the desire to obey the dictates of tradition
and religion. One such injunction emanates from the cult of the
ancestor, which, taking religion to be the act of reproducing the
lineage, requires women to bear many children [see "High Fertility in
Sub-Saharan Africa," by John C. Caldwell and Pat Caldwell; SCIENTIFIC
AMERICAN, May 1990].
Such traditions are often perpetuated by imitative behavior.
Procreation in closely knit communities is not only a private matter;
it is also a social activity, influenced by the cultural milieu. Often
there are norms encouraging high fertility rates that no household
desires unilaterally to break. (These norms may well have outlasted any
rationale they had in the past.) Consequently, so long as all others
aim at large families, no household on its own will wish to deviate.
Thus, a society can get stuck at a self-sustaining mode of behavior
that is characterized by high fertility and low educational attainment,
This does not mean that society will live with it forever. As
always, people differ in the extent to which they adhere to tradition.
Inevitably some, for one reason or another, will experiment, take risks
and refrain from joining the crowd. They are the nonconformists, and
they help to lead the way. An increase in female literacy could well
trigger such a process.
Still other motives for procreation involve viewing children as
productive assets. In a rural economy where avenues for saving are
highly restricted, parents value children as a source of security in
their old age. Mead Cain, previously at the Population Council, studied
this aspect extensively. Less discussed, at least until recently, is
another kind of motivation, explored by John C. Caldwell of the
Australian National University, Marc L. Nerlove of the University of
Maryland and Anke S. Meyer of the World Bank and by Karl-Goran Maler of
the Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics in Stockholm
and me. It stems from children's being valuable to their parents not
only for future income but also as a source of current income.
Third World countries are, for the most part, subsistence economies.
The rural folk eke out a living by using products gleaned directly from
plants and animals. Much labor is needed even for simple tasks. In
addition, poor rural households do not have access to modern sources of
domestic energy or tap water. In semi-arid and arid regions the water
supply may not even be nearby. Nor is fuel wood at hand when the
forests recede. In addition to cultivating crops, caring for livestock,
cooking food and producing simple marketable products, members of a
household may have to spend as much as five to six hours a day fetching
water and collecting fodder and wood.
Children, then, are needed as workers even when their parents are in
their prime. Small households are simply not viable; each one needs
many hands. In parts of India, children between 10 and 15 years have
been observed to work as much as one and a half times the number of
hours that adult males do. By the age of six, children in rural India
tend domestic animals and care for younger siblings, fetch water and
collect firewood, dung and fodder. It may well be that the usefulness
of each extra hand increases with declining availability of resources,
as measured by, say, the distance to sources of fuel and water.
The need for many hands can lead to a destructive situation,
especially when parents do not have to pay the full price of rearing
their children but share those costs with the community. In recent
years, mores that once regulated the use of local resources have
changed. Since time immemorial, rural assets such as village ponds and
water holes, threshing grounds, grazing fields, and local forests have
been owned communally. This form of control enabled households in
semi-arid regions to pool their risks. Elinor Ostrom of Indiana
University and others have shown that communities have protected such
local commons against overexploitation by invoking norms, imposing
fines for deviant behavior and so forth.
But the very process of economic development can erode traditional
methods of control. Increased urbanization and mobility can do so as
welt Social rules are also endangered by civil strife and by the
takeover of resources by landowners or the state. As norms degrade,
parents pass some of the costs of children on to the community by
overexploiting the commons. If access to shared resources continues,
parents produce too many children, which leads to greater crowding and
susceptibility to disease as well as to more pressure on environmental
resources. But no household, on its own, takes into account the harm it
inflicts on others when bringing forth another child.
Parental costs of procreation are also lower when relatives provide
a helping hand. Although the price of carrying a child is paid by the
mother, the cost of rearing the child is often shared among the
kinship. Caroline H. Bledsoe of Northwestern University and others have
observed that in much of sub-Saharan Africa fosterage is commonplace,
affording a form of insurance protection in semi-arid regions. In parts
of West Africa about a third of the children have been found to be
living with their kin at any given time. Nephews and nieces have the
same rights of accommodation and support as do biological offspring. In
recent work I have shown that this arrangement encourages couples to
have too many offspring if the parents' share of the benefits from
having children exceeds their share of the costs.
In addition, where conjugal bonds are weak, as they are in
sub-Saharan Africa, fathers often do not bear the costs of siring a
child. Historical demographers, such as E. A. Wrigley of the University
of Cambridge, have noted a significant difference between western
Europe in the 18th century and modern preindustrial societies. In the
former, marriage normally meant establishing a new household. This
requirement led to date marriages; it also meant that parents bore the
cost of rearing their children. Indeed, fertility rates in France
dropped before mortality rates registered a decline, before modern
family-planning techniques became available and before women became
literate.
The perception of both the low costs and high benefits of
procreation induces households to produce too many children. In certain
circumstances a disastrous process can begin. As the community's
resources are depleted, more hands are needed to gather fuel and water
for daily use. More children are then produced, further damaging the
local environment and in turn providing the household with an incentive
to enlarge. When this happens, fertility and environmental degradation
reinforce each other in an escalating spiral. By the time some
countervailing set of factors--whether public policy or diminished
benefits from having additional children--stops the spiral, millions of
lives may have suffered through worsening poverty.
Recent findings by the World Bank on sub-Saharan Africa have
revealed positive correlations among poverty, fertility and
deterioration of the local environment. Such data cannot reveal causal
connections, but they do support the idea of a positive-feedback
process such as I have described. Over fume, the effect of this spiral
can be large, as manifested by battles for resources [see
"Environmental Change and Violent Conflict," by T. F. Homer-Dixon, J.
H. Boutwell and G. W. Rathjens; SCIENTIFIC AMERICAN, February 1993].
The victims hit hardest among those who survive are society's
outcasts--the migrants and the dispossessed, some of whom in the course
of time become the emaciated beggars seen on the streets of large towns
and cities in underdeveloped countries. Historical studies by Robert W.
Fogel of the University of Chicago and theoretical explorations by
Debraj Ray of Boston University and me, when taken together, show that
the spiral I have outlined here is one way in which destitutes are
created. Emaciated beggars are not lazy; they have to husband their
precarious hold on energy. Having suffered from malnutrition, they
cease to be marketable.
Families with greater access to resources are, however, in a
position to limit their size and propel themselves into still higher
income levels. It is my impression that among the urban middle classes
in northern India, the transition to a lower fertility rate has already
been achieved. India provides an example of how the vicious cycle I
have described can enable extreme poverty to persist amid a growth in
well-being in the rest of society. The Matthew effect--"Unto every one
that hath shall be given, and he shall have abundance: but from him
that hath not shall be taken away even that which he hash"--works
relentlessly in impoverished countries.
This analysis suggests that the way to reduce fertility is to break
the destructive spiral. Parental demand for children rather than an
unmet need for contraceptives in large measure explains reproductive
behavior in developing countries. We should therefore try to identity
policies that will change the options available to men and women so
that couples choose to limit the number of offspring they produce.
In this regard, civil liberties, as opposed to coercion, play a
particular role. Some years ago my colleague Martin R. Weale and I
showed through statistical analysis that even in poor countries
political and civil liberties go together with improvements in other
aspects of life, such as income per person, life expectancy at birth
and infant survival rate. Thus, there are now reasons for thinking that
such liberties are not only desirable in themselves but also empower
people to flourish economically. Recently Adam Przeworski of the
University of Chicago demonstrated that fertility, as well, is lower in
countries where citizens enjoy more civil and political freedom. (An
exception is China, which represents only one country out of many in
this analysis.)
The most potent solution in semiarid regions of sub-Saharan Africa
and the Indian subcontinent is to deploy a number of policies
simultaneously. Family-planning services, especially when allied with
health services, and measures that empower women are certainly helpful.
As societal norms break down and traditional support systems falter,
those women who choose to change their behavior become financially and
socially more vulnerable. So a literacy and employment drive for women
is essential to smooth the transition to having fewer children.
But improving social coordination and directly increasing the
economic security of the poor are also essential. Providing cheap fuel
and potable water will reduce the usefulness of extra hands. When a
child becomes perceived as expensive, we may finally have a hope of
dislodging the rapacious hold of high fertility rates.
Each of the prescriptions suggested by our new perspective on the
links between population, poverty and environmental degradation is
desirable by itself, not just when we have those problems in mind. It
seems to me that this consonance of means and ends is a most agreeable
fact in what is otherwise a depressing field of study.
Some economists believe population growth is conducive to economic
growth. They cite statistics showing that, except in sub-Saharan
Africa, food production and gross income per head have generally grown
since the end of World War 11. Even in poor regions, infant survival
rate, literacy and life expectancy have improved, despite the
population's having grown much faster than in the past.
One weakness of this argument is that it is based on statistics that
ignore the depletion of the environmental resource base, on which all
production ultimately depends. This base includes soil and its cover,
freshwater, breathable air, fisheries and forests. No doubt it is
tempting to infer from past trends that human ingenuity can be relied
on to overcome the stresses that growing populations impose on the
natural environment.
Yet that is not likely to be the case. Societies already use an
enormous 40 percent of the net energy created by terrestrial
photosynthesis. Geoffrey M. Heal of Columbia University, John M.
Hartwick of Queens University and KarlGoran Maler of the Beijer
International Institute of Ecological Economics in Stockholm and I have
shown how to include environmental degradation in estimating the net
national product, or NNP. NNP is obtained by deducting from gross
national product the value of, for example, coal extracted or timber
logged.
This "green NNP" captures not only present production but also the
possibility of future production brought about by resources we
bequeath. Viewed through NNP, the future appears far less rosy. Indeed,
I know of no ecologist who thinks a population of 11 billion (projected
for the year 2050) can support itself at a material standard of living
of, say, today's representative American.
NUMBER OF CHILDREN
0-5 22.6
5.1-6 46.0
6.1-7 76.9
7 or more 65.7
NUMBER OF CHILDREN
0-5 18.1
5.1-6 27.1
6.1-7 31.7
7 or more 46.9
NUMBER OF CHILDREN
0-5 30.3
5.1-6 24.5
6.1-7 16.5
7 or more 10.6
TOTAL FERTILITY RATE around the world (the average number of
children a woman produces) generally increases with the
percentage of women in a country who are illiterate (top) or
work unpaid in family (middle). Fertility decreases when a
larger share of the paid employment belongs to women (bottom).
Bringing in a cash income may empower a woman in making decisions
within her family, allowing her to resist pressure to bear more
children.
REGION TOTAL FERTILITY RATE
SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 6 TO 8
INDIA 4
CHINA 2.3
JAPAN AND WESTERN
INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 1.5 TO 1.9
The chart (bottom) shows that fertility
is higher in countries t hat are poorer.
DIAGRAM: POVERTY, population growth and environmental degradation interact in a cyclic pattern (top).
PHOTO (COLOR): FETCHING WATER in Rajasthan, in the west of India,
takes up several hours a day for each household. As resources become
increasingly sparse and distant, additional hands become more valuable
for such daily tasks, creating a demand for families to have more
children. The burgeoning population puts more pressure on the
environment, spurring a need for even more offspring in a cycle of
increasing poverty, population and environmental damage.
PHOTO (COLOR): COLLECTING FIREWOOD is one way a brother and sister
in Eritrea contribute needed labor to a family. Households throughout
much of the Third World count on youngsters for a variety of tasks,
such as herding cows and goats, looking after younger siblings,
carrying water and searching for fuel and fodder. Older children often
work as much as one and a half times the number of hours as men. Many
are sold into "bonded labor," where they work to repay parents' debts.
PHOTO (COLOR): DESTITUTES sleep in the Indian city of Bombay, having
migrated from villages where spiraling poverty, population and
environmental decay have made life impossible. In time, some of these
dispossessed become the emaciated beggars and laborers common to urban
areas in the Third World.
POPULATION, NATURAL RESOURCES, AND DEVELOPMENT. Special issue of Ambio, Vol. 21, No. 1; February 1992.
AN INQUIRY INTO WELL-BEING AND DESTITUTION. Partha Dasgupta. Oxford University Press, 1993.
POPULATION: THE COMPLEX REALITY. Population Summit Report of the
World's Scientific Academies, Royal Society, London. North American
Press, 1994.
POPULATION, ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, AND THE ENVIRONMENT. Edited by
Kerstin Lindahl Kiessling and Hans Landberg. Oxford university Press,
1994.
WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT. World Bank, annual publication.
POVERTY, INSTITUTIONS AND THE ENVIRONMENTAL RESOURCE BASE. Partha
Dasgupta and Karl-Goran Maler in Handbook of Development Economics,
Vol. 3. Edited by T. N. Srinivasan et al. North Holland Publishing,
Amsterdam (in press).
~~~~~~~~
by Partha S. Dasgupta
PARTHA S. DASGUPTA, who was educated in Varanasi, Delhi and
Cambridge, is Frank Ramsey Professor of Economics at the University of
Cambridge and Fellow of St. John's College. He is also chairman of the
Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics of the Royal
Swedish Academy of Sciences in Stockholm and Fellow of the British
Academy. Dasgupta's research has ranged over various aspects of
environmental, resource and population economics, most recently poverty
and malnutrition.