GLOBAL WARMING: NEGLECTING THE COMPLEXITIES |
For three decades, I have been debating alternative solutions for
sustainable development with thousands of fellow scientists and policy
analysts--exchanges carried out in myriad articles and formal meetings.
Despite all that, I readily confess a lingering frustration:
uncertainties so infuse the issue of climate change that it is still
impossible to rule out either mild or catastrophic outcomes, let alone
provide confident probabilities for all the claims and counterclaims
made about environmental problems.
Even the most credible international assessment body, the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), has refused to
attempt subjective probabilistic estimates of future temperatures. This
has forced politicians to make their own guesses about the likelihood
of various degrees of global warming. Will temperatures in 2100
increase by 1.4 degrees Celsius or by 5.8? The difference means
relatively adaptable changes or very damaging ones.
Against this background of frustration, I began increasingly to hear
that a young Danish statistician in a political science department,
Bjorn Lomborg, had applied his skills in statistics to better determine
how serious environmental problems are, Of course, I was anxious to see
this highly publicized contribution--The Skeptical Environmentalist:
Measuring the Real State of the World. A "skeptical environmentalist"
is certainly the best kind, I mused, because uncertainties are so
endemic in these complex problems that suffer from missing data,
incomplete theory and nonlinear interactions. But the "real state of
the world"--that is a high bar to set, given the large range of
plausible outcomes.
And who is Lomborg, I wondered, and why haven't I come across him at
any of the meetings where the usual suspects debate costs, benefits,
extinction rates, carrying capacity or cloud feedback? I couldn't
recall reading any scientific or policy contributions from him either.
But there was this massive 515-page tome with a whopping 2,930 endnotes
to wade through. On page xx of his preface, Lomborg admits, "I am not
myself an expert as regards environmental problems"--truer words are
not found in the rest of the book, as I'll soon illustrate. I will
report primarily on the thick global warming chapter and its 600-plus
endnotes. That kind of deadweight of detail alone conjures at least the
trappings of comprehensive and careful scholarship. So how does the
reality of the text hold up to the pretense? I'm sure you can already
guess, but let me give some examples to make clear what I learned by
reading.
The climate chapter makes four basic arguments:
Climate science is very uncertain, but
nonetheless the real state of the science is that the sensitivity of
the climate to carbon dioxide will turn out to be at the low end of the
IPCC uncertainty range--which is for a warming of 1.5 to 4.5 degrees C
if carbon dioxide were to double and be held fixed over time.
Emissions scenarios, according to the IPCC, fall
into six "equally sound" alternative paths. These paths span a doubling
in carbon dioxide concentrations in 2100 up to more than tripling and
well beyond tripling in the 22nd century. Lomborg, however, dismisses
all but the lowest of the scenarios: "Temperatures will increase much
less than the maximum estimates from IPCC--it is likely that the
temperature will be at or below the B1 estimate [the lowest emissions
scenario] (less than 2° C in 2100) and the temperature will certainly
not increase even further into the twenty-second century."
Cost-benefit calculations show that although the
benefits of avoiding climate change could be substantial ($5 trillion
is the single figure Lomborg cites), this is not worth the cost to the
economy of trying to constrain fossil-fuel emissions (a $3-trillion to
$33-trillion range he pulls from the economics literature).
Asymmetrically, no range is given for the climate damages.
The Kyoto Protocol, which caps industrialized
countries' output of greenhouse gases, is too expensive. It would
reduce warming in 2100 by only a few tenths of a degree--"putting off
the temperature increase just six years." This number, though, is based
on a strawman policy that nobody has seriously proposed: Lomborg
extrapolates the Kyoto Protocol, which is applicable only up to 2012,
as the world's sole climate policy for another nine decades.
Before providing specifics of why I believe each of these assertions
is fatally flawed, I should say something about Lomborg's methods.
First, most of his nearly 3,000 citations are to secondary literature
and media articles. Moreover, even when cited, the peer-reviewed
articles come elliptically from those studies that support his rosy
view that only the low end of the uncertainty ranges will be plausible.
IPCC authors, in contrast, were subjected to three rounds of review by
hundreds of outside experts. They didn't have the luxury of reporting
primarily from the part of the community that agrees with their
individual views.
Second, it is ironic that in a popular book by a statistician one
can't find a clear discussion of the distinction among different types
of probabilities, such as frequentist and Bayesian (that is,
"objective'' and "subjective"). He uses the word "plausible" often,
but, curiously for a statistician, he never attaches any probability to
what is "plausible." The Third Assessment Report of the IPCC, on the
other hand, explicitly confronted the need to quantify all confidence
terms. Working Group I, for example, gave the term "likely" a 66 to 90
percent chance of occurring. Although the IPCC gives a wide range for
most of its projections, Lomborg generally dismisses these ranges,
focusing on the least serious outcomes. Not so much as one probability
is offered for the chance of a dangerous outcome, yet he makes a firm
assertion that climate "will certainly" not go beyond 2 degrees C
warming in the 22nd century--a conclusion at variance with the IPCC,
other national climate assessments and most recent studies in the field
of climate science.
Now let us look in more detail at the four major arguments he makes in this chapter.
Climate science. A typical example of Lomborg's
method is his paraphrase of a secondary source in reporting a 1989
Hadley Center paper in the journal Nature in which the researchers make
modifications to their climate model: "The programmers then improved
the cloud parameterizations in two places, and the model reacted by
reducing its temperature estimate from 5.2°C to 1.9° C." Had this been
first-rate scholarship, Lomborg would have consulted the original
article, in which the concluding sentence of the first paragraph
presents the authors' caveat: "Note that although the revised cloud
scheme is more detailed it is not necessarily more accurate than the
less sophisticated scheme."
In a similar vein, he cites Richard S. Lindzen's controversial
stabilizing feedback, or "iris effect," as evidence that the IPCC
climate sensitivity range should be reduced by a factor of almost
three. He fails either to understand this mechanism or to tell us that
it is based on only a few years of data in a small part of one ocean.
Extrapolating this small sample of data to the entire globe is like
extrapolating the strong destabilizing feedback over midcontinental
landmasses as snow melts during the spring--such an inappropriate
projection would likely increase estimates of climate sensitivity by a
factor of several.
As a final example, he quotes a controversial hypothesis from Danish
cloud physicists that solar magnetic events modulate cosmic rays and
produce "a clear connection between global low-level cloud cover and
incoming cosmic radiation." The Danish researchers use this hypothesis
to support an alternative to carbon dioxide for explaining recent
climate change. Lomborg fails to discuss--and I haven't seen it treated
by the authors of that speculative theory either--what such purported
changes to this cloud cover have done to the radiative balance of the
earth. Increasing clouds, it has been well known since papers by
Syukuro Manabe and Richard T. Wetherald in 1967 and myself in 1972, can
warm or cool the atmosphere depending on the height of the cloud tops,
the reflectivity of the underlying surface, the season and the
latitude. The reason the IPCC discounts this theory is that its
advocates have not demonstrated any radiative forcing sufficient to
match that of much more parsimonious theories, such as anthropogenic
forcing.
Emissions scenarios. Lomborg asserts that over
the next several decades new, improved solar machines and other
renewable technologies will crowd fossil fuels off the market. This
will be done so efficiently that the IPCC scenarios vastly overestimate
the chance for major increases in carbon dioxide. How I wish this would
turn out to be true! But wishes aren't analysis. One study is cited;
ignored is the huge body of economics work he later accepts to estimate
a range of costs if we were to implement emissions controls. In fact,
most of these economists strongly believe high emissions are quite
likely: they usually project carbon dioxide doubling to tripling (or
more) as "optimal" economic policy. I have attacked this literature for
failing to point out that climate policies that raise the price of
conventional fuels spur investments in alternative energy systems. But
such incentives need policies first--and Lomborg opposes those very
policies. No credible analyst can just assert that a
fossil-fuel-intensive scenario is not plausible--and, typically, he
gives no probability that it might occur.
Cost-benefit calculations. Lomborg's most
egregious distortions and poorest analyses are his citations of
cost-benefit calculations. First, he chides the governments that
modified the penultimate draft of the report from IPCC's Working Group
II. These modifications downgraded the significance of economic studies
that aggregate climate change damages. Lomborg says: "A political
decision stopped IPCC from looking at the total cost-benefit of global
warming." (As an aside, I should mention that it is strange he chose to
cite the penultimate and preapproval draft report in this case but
didn't mention the very first item in the approved summary--that recent
temperature trends have caused a discernible effect on plants and
animals. Even more puzzling is his failure to discuss ecological
impacts in general, focusing instead on health and agriculture, sectors
he thinks won't be much harmed by climate change of the minuscule
amount he predicts.)
The government representatives downgraded aggregate cost-benefit
studies for a reason: these studies fail to consider so many categories
of damages held to be important by political leaders as to render them
just a guideline on market-sector transactions, not the "total
cost-benefit" analysis Lomborg wants. A total analysis would have to
include the value of species lost, crucial ecosystem services degraded,
inequity created by the poor being hurt more than the rich (which
Lomborg does acknowledge), quality of life reduced (for example, a rise
in sea level driving small-island inhabitants from traditional
homelands), and likely changes to climatic extremes and variability.
Then again, Lomborg cites only one value for climate damages--$5
trillion--even though the same economics papers he refers to for costs
of climate policy generally acknowledge that climate damages can vary
from benefits up to catastrophic losses.
It is precisely because the responsible scientific community cannot
rule out such catastrophic outcomes at a high level of confidence that
climate mitigation polices are seriously proposed. And to give one
number--rather than a broad range--for avoided climate damages defies
explanation, especially when he does give a range for climate policy
costs. This range, however, is based on the economics literature but
ignores the findings of engineers. Engineers dispute the economists'
typical estimates because the economists fail to take into account
preexisting market imperfections such as energy-inefficient machines,
houses and processes. These engineering studies, including a famous one
by five U.S. Department of Energy laboratories-hardly environmental
radicals--suggest that climate policies that provide incentives to
replace inefficient equipment with more efficient state-of-the-art
products could actually reduce some emissions at below-zero costs.
The Kyoto Protocol. Lomborg's creation of a
100-year regime for a decade-long protocol is a distortion of the
climate policy process. Every IPCC report has noted that carbon dioxide
emissions need to be cut by more than 50 percent below most baseline
projections to avoid large increases in concentration in the late 21st
and 22nd centuries. Most analysts know "Kyoto extended'' can't make
such large cuts and that both developed and developing nations will
have to fashion cooperative and cost-effective solutions over time.
This will take a great deal of learning-by-doing: international
cooperation is not a common experience. Kyoto is a starting point. And
yet Lomborg, with his creation of a straw-man 100-year projection,
would squash even this first step.
So what then is "the real state of the world"? Clearly, it isn't
knowable in traditional statistical terms, even though subjective
estimates can be responsibly offered. The ranges presented by the IPCC
in its peer-reviewed reports give the best snapshot of the real state
of climate change: we could be lucky and see a mild effect or unlucky
and get the catastrophic outcomes. The IPCC frames the issue as a
risk-management decision about hedging. It is not the
everything-will-turn-out-fine affair that Lomborg would have us believe.
For such an interdisciplinary topic, the publisher would have been
wise to ask natural scientists as well as social scientists to review
the manuscript, which was published by the social science side of the
house. It's not surprising that the reviewers failed to spot Lomborg's
unbalanced presentation of the natural science, given the complexity of
the many intertwining fields. But that the natural scientists weren't
asked is a serious omission for a respectable publisher such as
Cambridge University Press.
Unfortunately, angry reviews such as this one will be the result.
Worse still, many laypeople and policymakers won't see the reviews and
could well be tricked into thinking thousands of citations and hundreds
of pages constitute balanced scholarship. A better rule of thumb is to
see who talks in ranges and subjective probabilities and to beware of
the myth busters and "truth tellers."
PHOTO (COLOR)
PHOTO (COLOR)
~~~~~~~~
By Stephen Schneider
Stephen Schneider, professor in the department of biological
sciences and senior fellow at the Institute for International Studies
at Stanford University, is editor of Climatic Change and the
Encyclopedia of Climate and Weather and lead author of several IPCC
chapters and the IPCC guidance paper on uncertainties.